APS209 Animal Behaviour
The Evolution of Communication
Aims
1.
Present examples of honest communication in animals.
2.
Describe the logic in how natural selection can favour honest communication.
3.
Present a detailed account of the logic behind begging as an honest signal of
need in chicks.
Objectives
1.
Learn specific examples.
2.
Understand why honest communication is an evolutionary puzzle.
3.
Understand the logic behind how cost or common interest can make a signal
honest.
We
humans communicate all the time. Is this communication honest? Consider two
situations. In the first, one person is selling a car to another and is telling
the potential buyer about it. In the second, a pilot and navigator are flying
an aircraft. In the first situation there is considerable incentive for
dishonesty in communication. The vendor may not tell the truth about the car
and the buyer may disguise his interest. But in the second situation there is
no incentive for dishonesty concerning communication needed to keep the aircraft
operating properly. Honest communication is also favoured in the waggle dance
communication between nestmate honeybees, or between cells and organs in your
body. In both cases there is nothing to benefit from making a dishonest signal.
The communicating parties benefit equally from any advantage to plane, colony
or body. Communication can still be honest or reliable, however, even if the
interests of the different communicating parties are not identical. Consider
the car sale. If the vendor tells obvious lies about the car the potential
buyer will be put off, so there is incentive in being reasonably honest.
(Society may also impose laws preventing sellers from dishonestly describing
their goods, but that is another matter.)
Ravens who have found an animal
carcass in the Maine woods sometimes call others to the feast by yelling.
Yelling is a deliberate and honest signal that food is available. How can
natural selection favour one animal making a signal that attracts a competitor
to food? It seems that yelling is not always favoured. If a resident raven
finds a carcass on its territory it does not yell and may be able to have it
all to itself, or to share it with its mate. But if a non-resident bird finds a
carcass it yells to attract other non-residents. The attracted birds are too
many to be driven off by the territory owners.
Nestling birds often beg loudly.
Parents often give more food to chicks that beg more. Why do they do this? If
chicks that beg the loudest are also the hungriest then it makes sense for the
parents to feed them more because a piece of food given to a hungry chick will
normally increase its survival more that when given to a well-fed chick. By
doing this, parents have more surviving offspring. But if parents give more
food to chicks that beg more, what stops well-fed chicks from also begging as
loudly as hungry chicks? There should be no physiological reason why they could
not make as much noise. The puzzle can be resolved when we realise that begging
also has a cost. Not only the energy of making the calls but also the
attraction of predators. (And remember inclusive
fitness. It is not just your own death, but that of your relatives, which
is costly to cause.) The same amount of noise made by two chicks, one hungry
and one well fed, would presumably be equally harmful in attracting predators.
But the benefit of the begging would be greater to the hungry chick. Thus the
optimum begging intensity would be greater for a hungrier chick. Paradoxically,
it is the cost of making the signal that can keep begging an honest signal of
need. (Question—if begging had zero cost what would be the evolutionary
consequences of this for chicks and parents in terms of begging intensity and
parental response?)
By using simple figures, the
cost-benefit logic underlying this argument can easily be seen. We can also see
that if the cost of begging is reduced then the optimum begging intensity
rises. One way that the cost can be reduced is via extra-pair parentage. This
lowers the relatedness among chicks and so lowers the cost of nest predation to
a begging chick, which would value the lives of the other chicks in the nest
less. Data support this prediction. Chicks beg more loudly in species in which
extra-pair parentage is higher.
A similar cost-benefit argument can
be made for male displays to attract females. Some displays, such as the
peacock’s tail, are so elaborate that they actually handicap the male. If the handicap is more costly to make for a
low-quality male than for a high-quality male, then the optimum size of the
display (handicap) will correlate with male quality. In other words, male
display can be a revealing signal of male quality when the display is costly.
Some signals are honest because they
are uncheatable. This is referred to as an index
by Maynard-Smith and Harper (2003). For example, larger males may be able
to make louder or deeper calls than small males. In many animals, from red deer
to toads, deep male calls can deter rivals because a deep call will normally
mean that a large male is making them. It is difficult to cheat on body size,
although animals can cheat to some extent by inflating their abdomen, puffing
out their chest, or making their hair stand on end. In doing this they are
trying to look as large as possible, because large size is correlated with
fighting ability in males and fecundity in females. In some spiders contests
are decided by body size. A resident spider in a web can gauge the weight of an
intruder by its effect on the web. Body weight is a reliable indicator of size.
The book Animal Signals (Maynard Smith & Harper 2003) mainly addresses
the question of honesty in communication. It categorises three basic ways that
a signal can be honest or reliable.
common interest e.g.
communication within your body, bee dance, pilot & navigator
handicap/cost e.g.
costly chick begging, male displays that are handicaps.
index of quality e.g.
uncheatable indices of size such as the roar of a male red deer
Finally, it is worth remembering that communication can be
subject to deception and conflict. The bolas spider attracts male moths by
producing the pheromone made by female moths to attract males. Some predatory
female fireflies mimic the flashing signal used by females of other species to
attract males. These are known as “fire fly femme fatales”. Why do the males
allow themselves to be attracted to a predator? Presumably, the predators are
rather rare in relation to the legitimate signallers. On average, a male
increases his fitness by responding to the signal, even if a small proportion
of the signals are deceptive and lead the amorous male to his doom, rather than
to a receptive female.
References
See Chapter 9 in Alcock’s Animal
Behavior (2009).
See also: Maynard Smith, J., Harper, D.
2003. Animal Signals. Oxford University Press
Bug control organizations have some expertise in disposing of undesirable rodents and bugs with the utilization of synthetic compounds. They likewise bargain in anticipation to stay away from new issues grabbing hold, like putting down traps and routinely showering regions inclined to pervasion. pest control for business
ReplyDelete